皮皮学,免费搜题
登录
logo - 刷刷题
搜题
【单选题】
Changes in the volume of unemployment are governed by three fundamental forces: the growth of the labor force, the increase in output per man-hour, and the growth of total demand for goods and services. Changes in the average hours of work enter in exactly parallel fashion but have been quantitatively less significant. As productivity rises, less labor is required per dollar of national product, or more goods and services can be produced with the same number of goods. If output does not grow, employment will certainly fall if production increases more rapidly than productivity (less any decline in average hours worked)employment must rise. But the labor force grows, too. Unless gross national product( total final expenditure for goods and services corrected for price changes) rises more rapidly than the sum of productivity increase and labor force growth (again modified for any change in hours of work), the increase in employment will be inadequate to absorb the growth in the labor force. Inevitably the unemployment rate will increase. Only when total production expands faster than the rate of labor force growth plus the rate of productivity increase and minus the rate at which average annual hours fall does the unemployment rate fall. Increases in productivity were more important than growth of the labor force as sources of the wide gains in output experienced in the period from the end of the war to the mid-sixties. These increases in potential production simply were not matched by increases in demand adequate to maintain steady full employment. Except for the recession years of 1949, 1954, and 1958, the rate of economic growth exceeded the rate of productivity increase. However, in the late 1950s productivity and labor force were increasing more rapidly than usual, while the growth of output was slower than usual. This accounted for the change in employment rates. But if part of the national purpose is to reduce and contain unemployment, arithmetic is not enough. We must know which of the basic factors we can control and which we wish to control. Unemployment would have risen more slowly or fallen more rapidly if productivity had in creased more slowly, or the labor force had increased more slowly, or the hours of work had fallen more steeply, or total output had grown more rapidly. These are not independent factors, however, and a change in any of them might have caused change in the other. A society can choose to reduce the growth of productivity, and it can probably find ways to frustrate its own creativity. However, while a reduction in the growth of productivity at the expense of potential output might result in higher employment in the short run, the long-run effect on the national interest would be disastrous. We must also give consideration to the fact that hidden beneath national averages is continuous movement into, out of, between, and within labor markets. For example, 15 years ago, the average number of persons in the labor force was 74 million, with about 70 million employed and 3.9 million unemployed. Yet 14 million experienced some term or unemployment in that year. Some were new entrants to the labor fore others were laid off temporarily, the remainder were those who were permanently or indefinitely severed from their jobs. Thus, the average number unemployed during a year understates the actual volume of involunatary displacement that occurs. High unemployment is not an inevitable result of the pace of technological change but the consequence of passive public policy. We can anticipate a moderate increase in the labor force accompained by a slow and irregular decline in hours or work. It follows that the output of the economy--and the aggregate demand to buy it--must grow by more than 4 percent a year just to prevent the unemployment rate from rising, and by even more if the unemployment rate is to fall further. Yet our
A.
productivity rises at the same rate as growth of the labor force
B.
productivity and labor force increase at a greater rate than output
C.
output exceeds productivity
D.
rate of economic growth is less than the number of man-hours required
手机使用
分享
复制链接
新浪微博
分享QQ
微信扫一扫
微信内点击右上角“…”即可分享
反馈
参考答案:
举一反三
【单选题】有些人在面对应激事件时易采用“钻牛角尖”的方式应对,这种应对方式属于( )
A.
自我防御反应
B.
情绪反应
C.
行为反应
D.
生理反应又
E.
认知反直
【单选题】有些人在面对应激事件时易采用“钻牛角尖”的方式应对,这种应对方式属于
A.
情绪反应
B.
行为反应
C.
生理反应
D.
认知反应
【判断题】TCR是T细胞表面识别特异性抗原的蛋白分子。
A.
正确
B.
错误
【单选题】在一条离体神经纤维的中段施加电刺激,使其兴奋。下图表示刺激时的膜内外电位变化和所产生的神经冲动传导方向(横向箭头)。其中正确的是( )
A.
B.
C.
D.
D
【单选题】有些人在面对应激事件时易采用“钻牛角尖”方式,这种应对方式属于
A.
自我防御反应
B.
生理反应
C.
认知反应
D.
行为反应
E.
情绪反应
【单选题】在一条离体神经纤维的中段施加电刺激,使其兴奋,下图表示刺激时的膜内外电位变化和所产生的神经冲动传导方向(横向箭头表示传导方向)。其中正确的是 [     ]
A.
B.
C.
【单选题】在一条离体神经纤维的中段施加电刺激,使其兴奋。下列四项表示刺激时的膜内外电位变化和所产生的神经冲动传导方向(横向箭头表示传导方向),其中正确的是 [     ]
A.
B.
C.
【单选题】在一条离体神经纤维的中段施加电刺激,使其兴奋,如图表示刺激时的膜内电位变化和所产生的兴奋传导方向(横向箭头表示传导方向),其中正确的是 [     ]
A.
B.
C.
【单选题】有些人在面对应激事件时易采用'钻牛角尖'的方式应对,这种应对方式属于
A.
自我防御反应
B.
情绪反应
C.
行为反应
D.
生理反应
E.
认知反应
【单选题】在一条离体神经纤维的中段施加电刺激,使其兴奋。下图表示刺激时的膜内外电位变化和所产生的神经冲动传导方向(横向箭头),其中正确的是()
A.
选项A
B.
选项B
C.
选项C
D.
选项D
相关题目:
参考解析:
知识点:
题目纠错 0
发布
创建自己的小题库 - 刷刷题